Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore
In this paper, we take another approach to accounting for the sources of Singapore’s economic growth by being explicit about the channels through which Singapore, as a technological follower, benefits from international R&D spillovers. Taking into account the channels through which technology de...
Saved in:
Main Authors: | , |
---|---|
Format: | text |
Language: | English |
Published: |
Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University
2006
|
Subjects: | |
Online Access: | https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/899 https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/context/soe_research/article/1898/viewcontent/growth.pdf |
Tags: |
Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
|
Institution: | Singapore Management University |
Language: | English |
id |
sg-smu-ink.soe_research-1898 |
---|---|
record_format |
dspace |
spelling |
sg-smu-ink.soe_research-18982019-05-01T09:25:35Z Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore HO, Kong Weng HOON, Hian Teck In this paper, we take another approach to accounting for the sources of Singapore’s economic growth by being explicit about the channels through which Singapore, as a technological follower, benefits from international R&D spillovers. Taking into account the channels through which technology developed in the G5 countries diffuses to technological followers, we show that 57.5 percent of Singapore’s real GDP per worker growth rate over the 1970-2002 period is due to multifactor productivity growth. In particular, about 52 percent of the growth is accounted for by an increase in the effectiveness of accessing ideas developed by the technology leaders through improvement in our educational quality and increase in machinery imports and foreign direct investment from the G5 countries. We also find that capital accumulation that takes the form of imports of machinery as well as foreign direct investment from the G5 countries enhances the effectiveness of technology transfer thus raising the rate of return to capital. Compared to the rate of return to capital inferred from the traditional Solow growth model with purely exogenous technological progress of 10.8 percent, taking into account the technology transfer channel raises the implied rate of return to 13 percent 2006-06-01T07:00:00Z text application/pdf https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/899 https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/context/soe_research/article/1898/viewcontent/growth.pdf http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ Research Collection School Of Economics eng Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University Asian Studies Finance Macroeconomics |
institution |
Singapore Management University |
building |
SMU Libraries |
continent |
Asia |
country |
Singapore Singapore |
content_provider |
SMU Libraries |
collection |
InK@SMU |
language |
English |
topic |
Asian Studies Finance Macroeconomics |
spellingShingle |
Asian Studies Finance Macroeconomics HO, Kong Weng HOON, Hian Teck Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore |
description |
In this paper, we take another approach to accounting for the sources of Singapore’s economic growth by being explicit about the channels through which Singapore, as a technological follower, benefits from international R&D spillovers. Taking into account the channels through which technology developed in the G5 countries diffuses to technological followers, we show that 57.5 percent of Singapore’s real GDP per worker growth rate over the 1970-2002 period is due to multifactor productivity growth. In particular, about 52 percent of the growth is accounted for by an increase in the effectiveness of accessing ideas developed by the technology leaders through improvement in our educational quality and increase in machinery imports and foreign direct investment from the G5 countries. We also find that capital accumulation that takes the form of imports of machinery as well as foreign direct investment from the G5 countries enhances the effectiveness of technology transfer thus raising the rate of return to capital. Compared to the rate of return to capital inferred from the traditional Solow growth model with purely exogenous technological progress of 10.8 percent, taking into account the technology transfer channel raises the implied rate of return to 13 percent |
format |
text |
author |
HO, Kong Weng HOON, Hian Teck |
author_facet |
HO, Kong Weng HOON, Hian Teck |
author_sort |
HO, Kong Weng |
title |
Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore |
title_short |
Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore |
title_full |
Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore |
title_fullStr |
Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore |
title_full_unstemmed |
Growth Accounting for a Follower-Economy in a World of Ideas: The Example of Singapore |
title_sort |
growth accounting for a follower-economy in a world of ideas: the example of singapore |
publisher |
Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University |
publishDate |
2006 |
url |
https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/899 https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/context/soe_research/article/1898/viewcontent/growth.pdf |
_version_ |
1770569333339062272 |