Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies
The ratio of hirings to vacancies in the U.S. has the following establishment level properties: (i) it steeply rises with employment growth rate; (ii) falls with establishment size; and (iii) rises with worker turnover rate. The standard Diamond-Mortensen Pissarides (DMP) matching model is not compa...
Saved in:
Main Author: | |
---|---|
Format: | text |
Language: | English |
Published: |
Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University
2017
|
Subjects: | |
Online Access: | https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/1990 https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/context/soe_research/article/2989/viewcontent/workerselection.pdf |
Tags: |
Add Tag
No Tags, Be the first to tag this record!
|
Institution: | Singapore Management University |
Language: | English |
id |
sg-smu-ink.soe_research-2989 |
---|---|
record_format |
dspace |
spelling |
sg-smu-ink.soe_research-29892021-03-12T07:11:03Z Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies BAYDUR, Ismail The ratio of hirings to vacancies in the U.S. has the following establishment level properties: (i) it steeply rises with employment growth rate; (ii) falls with establishment size; and (iii) rises with worker turnover rate. The standard Diamond-Mortensen Pissarides (DMP) matching model is not compatible with these observations. This paper augments selection of workers prior to hiring into a random matching model with multi-worker firms. In the calibrated model, worker selection accounts for about 30% of the variation in the hiring-vacancy ratio observed in the data. Compared to the standard model, the worker selection model has both qualitative and quantitative policy implications. A hiring subsidy reduces the unemployment rate substantially in the worker selection model, whereas the reduction in the unemployment rate is very small in the standard model. The two models also differ regarding the impact of the hiring subsidy across firms. The worker selection model implies that firms that have initially high worker turnover rates experience proportionally higher worker turnover rates after the subsidy. In contrast, the standard model predicts that the worker turnover rate increases proportionally more at firms with initially lower worker turnover rates. 2017-01-01T08:00:00Z text application/pdf https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/1990 info:doi/10.1257/mac.20140260 https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/context/soe_research/article/2989/viewcontent/workerselection.pdf http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by-nc-nd/4.0/ Research Collection School Of Economics eng Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University equilibrium unemployment cyclical behavior labor-market turnover costs firm dynamics search efficiency wages size Labor Economics Macroeconomics |
institution |
Singapore Management University |
building |
SMU Libraries |
continent |
Asia |
country |
Singapore Singapore |
content_provider |
SMU Libraries |
collection |
InK@SMU |
language |
English |
topic |
equilibrium unemployment cyclical behavior labor-market turnover costs firm dynamics search efficiency wages size Labor Economics Macroeconomics |
spellingShingle |
equilibrium unemployment cyclical behavior labor-market turnover costs firm dynamics search efficiency wages size Labor Economics Macroeconomics BAYDUR, Ismail Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
description |
The ratio of hirings to vacancies in the U.S. has the following establishment level properties: (i) it steeply rises with employment growth rate; (ii) falls with establishment size; and (iii) rises with worker turnover rate. The standard Diamond-Mortensen Pissarides (DMP) matching model is not compatible with these observations. This paper augments selection of workers prior to hiring into a random matching model with multi-worker firms. In the calibrated model, worker selection accounts for about 30% of the variation in the hiring-vacancy ratio observed in the data. Compared to the standard model, the worker selection model has both qualitative and quantitative policy implications. A hiring subsidy reduces the unemployment rate substantially in the worker selection model, whereas the reduction in the unemployment rate is very small in the standard model. The two models also differ regarding the impact of the hiring subsidy across firms. The worker selection model implies that firms that have initially high worker turnover rates experience proportionally higher worker turnover rates after the subsidy. In contrast, the standard model predicts that the worker turnover rate increases proportionally more at firms with initially lower worker turnover rates. |
format |
text |
author |
BAYDUR, Ismail |
author_facet |
BAYDUR, Ismail |
author_sort |
BAYDUR, Ismail |
title |
Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
title_short |
Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
title_full |
Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
title_fullStr |
Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
title_full_unstemmed |
Worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
title_sort |
worker selection, hiring, and vacancies |
publisher |
Institutional Knowledge at Singapore Management University |
publishDate |
2017 |
url |
https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/soe_research/1990 https://ink.library.smu.edu.sg/context/soe_research/article/2989/viewcontent/workerselection.pdf |
_version_ |
1770573490905153536 |